Jennifer Burns on Milton Friedman and Ayn Rand (Ep. 197)

The indelible influence of two public intellectuals

Jennifer Burns is a professor of history at Stanford who works at the intersection of intellectual, political, and cultural history. She’s written two biographies Tyler highly recommends: her 2009 book, Goddess of the Market: Ayn Rand and the American Right and her latest, Milton Friedman: The Last Conservative, provides a nuanced look into the influential economist and public intellectual.

Tyler and Jennifer start by discussing how her new portrait of Friedman caused her to reassess him, his lasting impact in statistics, whether he was too dogmatic, his shift from academic to public intellectual, the problem with Two Lucky People, what Friedman’s courtship of Rose Friedman was like, how Milton’s family influenced him, why Friedman opposed Hayek’s courtesy appointment at the University of Chicago, Friedman’s attitudes toward friendship, his relationship to fiction and the arts, and the prospects for his intellectual legacy. Next, they discuss Jennifer’s previous work on Ayn Rand, including whether Rand was a good screenwriter, which is the best of her novels, what to make of the sex scenes in Atlas Shrugged and The Fountainhead, how Rand and Mises got along, and why there’s so few successful businesswomen depicted in American fiction. They also delve into why fiction seems so much more important for the American left than it is for the right, what’s driving the decline of the American conservative intellectual condition, what she will do next, and more.

Watch the full conversation

Subscribe on Apple Podcasts, Spotify, or your favorite podcast app to be notified when a new episode releases.

Recorded August 30th, 2023

Read the full transcript

TYLER COWEN: Hello, everyone, and welcome back to Conversations with Tyler. Today I’m honored to be talking with Jennifer Burns, who is a history professor at Stanford University. She has a new book out, which I just loved. It is called Milton Friedman: The Last Conservative, and her earlier book I also like very much, that is, Goddess of the Market: Ayn Rand and the American Right. Jennifer, welcome.

JENNIFER BURNS: Thanks so much for having me. I’m really looking forward to our conversation.

COWEN: There’s so much Milton Friedman one can read. There’s a reasonable amount of him on YouTube. Overall, how did writing this book cause you to reassess Friedman? What’s the delta?

BURNS: That’s a great question. I came in really interested in him as the public figure, the YouTuber, as it were. Over time, I got more interested in him as the economist. I came to understand how much that public Friedman was the tip of the iceberg on a much bigger base of inquiry, research, thinking — not just in economics but in many dimensions of economics. That was one thing I hadn’t fully appreciated: Friedman the economist.

Then, as time went on, one thing I came more to appreciate was the way he had both a very consistent message and some change in development in his thought — the dynamism and stability at the same time.

COWEN: Now, Friedman’s earliest work on math and statistics — why was that important, and when was that?

BURNS: Friedman, very early in his life, was choosing between the field of mathematics and the field of economics. When he came into economics, it was really transitioning away from political economy, which was rooted in 19th-century philosophy, ethics, considerations of government, to a more quantitative field.

That shift would happen around Friedman, and what was important is that he was there on the ground floor of that in the 1930s. He was trained by some of the most preeminent mathematical economists of his generation at Columbia, not necessarily at Chicago. Over time, he came to reject that approach.

This is something not a lot of people, particularly economists, know about Friedman. But it was significant that he rejected it, not out of ignorance but from a position of understanding mathematical economics, having actually made his mark early in his career with several papers and then deciding that, intellectually, this was unsatisfying, and this was not providing him with the portrait of the world that he thought economics could reveal if done the way that he ultimately did it.

COWEN: His early work on stats — that’s still cited by mathematicians, right?

BURNS: Yes. There’s something called the Friedman Test, which is still included in software packages. One, he was there in the first era of mathematical economics. He was also there on the ground of really the first era of big data. During the Great Depression, the government was struggling to understand what had gone wrong and how to fix it. One approach they took was to gather as much data as they possibly could on consumption. What are ordinary Americans buying, spending?

They ended up with millions of punch cards. They had this very rudimentary technology, and Friedman was one of the analysts hired by the federal government in the mid ’30s to figure this information out, basically, to process this data. As he grappled with that in his workaday life, he came up with a couple of statistical — shortcuts is to be a bit flippant — but techniques to enable you to get through data very quickly, and those became important papers.

He also had a second discovery that I talk about in the book, when he was working at the Statistical Research Group, which was a secret wartime agency. This was a similar task in that they were given a problem by the army that said, basically, how can we know if our munitions work? How can we test them more efficiently, given that we’re fighting the biggest war we’ve ever fought on two different fronts?

He came up with what he called the super colossal test, and he was able to conceptualize it and design it. But he wasn’t able to prove it mathematically because, although he was a skilled mathematician, he said, “I’m not there. I need a little bit of a better mathematician.” He ended up bringing in Abraham Wald to finalize the results of the idea they had come up with, and this became known as Sequential Analysis and ended up being a huge boon to the US military in terms of enabling them to test their ordnance and move forward.

It’s fascinating in terms of Friedman’s later life — his earlier career, his intellectual discoveries are very much embedded in a growing federal government that’s growing because of the Great Depression, that’s growing because of World War II. This is what enables him to develop that statistical prowess. It gives him a very strong reputation, a field of economics.

But what’s interesting is, within five years of that, he’s turning his back on those techniques and methods and saying, “This isn’t applicable to understanding human economic behavior. These mathematical models and statistical techniques — these aren’t enough.”

COWEN: What’s the when and how of Friedman starting to become some glimmer of, say, the Milton Friedman of the ’70s and ’80s? What leads him to make the shift and decide, “Well, I’m going to be some version of America’s leading public intellectual and take on this heroic role, change the world and everything else”?

BURNS: I think he had opportunities to do that throughout his life, some of which he took and some of which he passed on. But I would say he had a model of that very young in his life when he was a graduate student, in the figure of Henry Simons, who is one of these forgotten figures in the history of economics, who I became absolutely fascinated by.

Henry Simons had a book that was a big deal in the 1930s. It was called A Positive Program for Laissez Faire. It was an effort to talk about principles of liberalism — what we would call classical liberalism — and apply them in the New Deal context and use them to critique the New Deal.

Then Simons became very actively involved in promoting what was called the Chicago Plan, which was a monetary solution to the Great Depression. It actually would’ve been a radical reformulation of the banking sector. Simons had friends in high places, was pushing this through the political system. I think that was an early model for Friedman.

At the same time — it was about the 1950s — at one point, he was offered a berth on Eisenhower’s Council of Economic Advisers, and he said no. He basically wanted to do his work at the University of Chicago. At that point, it didn’t feel done. He didn’t want to step into the public realm.

I think he was always paying attention, always thinking about it. It’s really with his connection to Barry Goldwater that he has the first phase of being a public intellectual. That also comes after he’s completed, with Anna Schwartz, his magnum opus, A Monetary History of the United States. I think he was both strategic and deliberate in that he wanted to do his major scientific work before he stepped into the public realm.

There are two phases of him as a public intellectual. There’s the ’60s to the ’70s, and then there’s the post-Nobel Prize, when he’s retired and when he is still out there, but that’s when he’s on Donahue and has more of a presence in the Republican establishment.

COWEN: There’s a letter you cite from Wesley Clair Mitchell — maybe it’s from 1947 — where Mitchell basically says, “Friedman is too dogmatic. He did this study of incomes of the medical profession, and we can’t really trust it because he’s looking for a particular conclusion.” What do you make of that account for Mitchell? Was Mitchell himself biased? Friedman was just flat-out right, Friedman was too dogmatic — what do you think?

BURNS: I think about this a lot. I found this letter just very startling, and I include quite a bit of it in the book, when Mitchell says to Burns —

COWEN: This is Arthur Burns.

BURNS: Arthur Burns wanted to hire Friedman on the National Bureau of Economic Research, and Wesley Mitchell basically said no. He said, “He can’t be trusted, not in that he lacks integrity, but that he’s so committed to what he wants to see that he will selectively interpret the data.” It’s interesting because I see in his letters with him and Schwartz, at one point he says to her, “We didn’t just go and take a bunch of monetary statistics to see what we wanted to see. We had a hypothesis about what we would see. We went in and gathered data to test a hypothesis.”

As I was reading this, I was thinking, he doesn’t have a consciousness of what we would call selective reading or bias or selective recognition of facts to fit a preexisting . . . He didn’t see that as a pitfall or a problem. On the other hand, he does say in some of his later work, “Look, everyone has a point of view. Everyone comes from a place.” I wouldn’t say it’s radical perspectivalism, but it’s an awareness that you stand somewhere, and we can’t get away from this. Therefore, we just have to proceed anyhow.

I think he truly believed he was testing, to the best of his ability, his priors, and he believed that he was willing to revise them. I think in some cases he was. In other cases, what he found matched his priors. I don’t think that invalidates his whole intellectual project, but I think it’s interesting — his level of confidence in his ability to evaluate his own thinking. At the same time, I also think that is one way to do science. You have a hypothesis; you go in with a hypothesis and you see if it’s true. That was very much how he operated.

COWEN: Putting aside co-authored works, how do you understand Rose Friedman, his wife, to have influenced Milton’s career?

BURNS: Putting aside co-authored works. [laughs]

COWEN: A deep psychological way in which this all fits together. Clearly, they wrote things together. You mentioned she shaped or maybe even edited a lot of his Newsweek columns. At the margin, was she telling Milton, “Be more out there,” or “Retreat to your academic life,” or what’s she doing?

BURNS: She was definitely telling him to be more out there. I don’t think we’d have Milton the public intellectual without Rose, and that is specifically putting together Capitalism and Freedom. I was never able to untangle exactly what she did because that portion of the archive is missing — I think, not coincidentally. But both of them said she’s the one who put this book together. She went into the notes and made it into a book. I don’t think he would’ve done that.

She and his son, David, also convinced him to do Newsweek. They said, “You owe it to yourself, to the country. You’ve got to do this.” They really pushed him. I think he would not have been so prominent in the public eye without her. I think there are other contributions just allowing him to be really singularly focused on his work because she took care of everything else.

COWEN: How else did David Friedman, Milton’s son, influence him?

BURNS: As far as I can tell, David was an important connection for Milton Friedman to the student libertarian movement that coalesced, really, around ending the draft. David was involved in conservative student organizations at Harvard and then at Chicago, where he was a graduate student.

Friedman always had a connection to those communities. There are some times, I forget exactly where, but I’ve seen some libertarian material from the ’70s where David convinced Friedman to do an interview or call in to a conference. For libertarians in the late ’60s and ’70s, Friedman was a bit of a court intellectual. He was too statist for their tastes, but he stayed engaged with them. I think David was the conduit. David, at that point, was much more of an anarcho-capitalist than his father. I think he helped the elder Friedman keep his pulse on what was happening with a younger and more radical student movement.

COWEN: What was Milton’s courtship of Rose Friedman like?

BURNS: It started because of their names. Rose’s was originally Rose Director, and Milton Friedman, so they were seated next to each other in class. It was very much a study-buddy thing at first. I think Milton always had his eye on Rose. Rose was the only woman in a class of 30-some economists. She had, I’m sure, more than one suitor, although she doesn’t go into any detail in this. They studied together; they spent time together.

There’s an anecdote I recount in the book, where at the end of their first year in graduate school, as they were getting ready to depart for the summer, Milton tried to kiss Rose, and she rebuffed him. Then they were apart for a year, and when they came back together, things had changed, and she was ready to be in a relationship with him.

Then they were in a sextet of couples who spent all their time together. There’s then a period where it seems unclear what is going to happen next. I don’t think that Milton Friedman ever seriously had another girlfriend or considered another partner, and same for Rose. But it was the 1930s. Economic prospects were slim, and it was very much a cultural more that a man had to be able to support his wife and children before he would consider marriage.

So there’s a couple-year period where they’re still together, and Rose is thinking they’re about to get married, and Milton is not so sure. I think at some point, his friends were like, “What are you doing? Just wise up and marry her.” At some point, she called his bluff and said, “Look, we have to get married,” and they did. I don’t think there was ever any question of the love. I think it was just there was some hesitation because of their economic fortunes.

COWEN: How is it that you read their joint memoir, Two Lucky People? Is the title jesting like, they were lucky? When I read the book, I was surprised how bored I was.

BURNS: [laughs]

COWEN: I wasn’t sure, well, they did this because they wanted to manicure the story, which is super upright to begin with, to be clear, as I think you would agree. Or, is it actually how they approach things? When I read Quine’s memoir, I was super bored, and I concluded tentatively, well, maybe Quine was just boring. How do you think about this?

BURNS: Yes. Many people, even those who love Milton Friedman, find this not a very compelling read. It’s more of a travelogue. I read it as a book that’s fundamentally generous in that everybody was someone they enjoyed, the conversations were spirited, the arguments were friendly, which is simply not very accurate to how their life was lived. I’ll provide an anecdote about that.

Though, as I think of it, this is a couple in their 90s that’s had a good life. They’re looking back, they’re reflecting; they’re not trying to settle scores. They’re trying to put the most positive spin on anything possible. I think it’s generous in that spirit, but it’s not very accurate. After a while, I realized the biggest person that I was writing against in my biography was not another biographer, but it was Two Lucky People. [laughs] That was the text that everybody had in mind that was just simply not accurate in many ways.

I’ll tell you two ways that I see it as being inaccurate. One is, Friedman recounts an episode of him testifying to Congress. He says — and this is in the early 1940s — “I had no idea how Keynesian I was.” There’s been maybe 5 to 10 books and articles that have jumped off that to say, “Well, Milton Friedman was once a Keynesian, and then he had some type of conversion.” I do not see that in any of the records I’ve looked at.

I go into some detail, both in the text and more detail in the footnotes, about why I don’t think this is accurate. Friedman’s looking at his congressional testimony or reads it in five minutes and says, “Oh, this sounds Keynesian,” from his vantage point in the ’90s. It’s not an accurate depiction of his views or of his location in American economics in the 1940s, but it’s taken as gospel because he said it.

The other thing I would say — I talk about this in some detail as well — in the 1950s, there was a large conflict at the University of Chicago between Friedman and a group associated with the economics department, the Cowles Commission. That was actually a group of mathematical economists, many leftist in nature, and Friedman didn’t like their economics, and he didn’t like their politics. It was basically an extended turf war.

They mentioned this briefly, but when you dig down a little bit more, they mentioned Tjalling Koopmans, who’s the leader of Cowles at that point. It’s along the lines of “spirited discussion, some conflict.” In reality, there are accounts that indicate Koopmans went through a mental breakdown as part of his conflict with Friedman and had to take time away from the university, had to go to a music camp to rest his mind.

Friedman was successful in getting their Rockefeller grant canceled, basically cutting off their funding sources. You would know there was conflict, but you wouldn’t know that it was very intense and dark conflict. You don’t see that in the memoir — which, again, may be to his credit. He’s trying not to exhume all the negative things he did, but he’s glossing over how intense . . . This was like academic street fighting. It really was.

COWEN: I’m struck by your portrait of the profession in the ’40s and ’50s, how petty it was, how much people would hold up dissertations, how much individual personalities probably mattered more then than they do now. Is that the impression you have of the work you did on that time? It just sounds horrible and you think, “Oh, things have gotten worse.” [laughs] But actually, maybe they’ve gotten better.

BURNS: It was professionalizing. Economics was professionalizing. In the absence of strong professional norms, there was a lot of room for personality, for prejudice, for all this sort of thing. There are several economists who were hired without dissertations. You could be hired and have a good career without actually finishing your dissertation, which is completely unheard of today.

The story I go into in some detail involves Anna Schwartz and how the Columbia faculty simply would not give her a PhD. They just wouldn’t do it. They could not be convinced that she deserved a PhD. It’s very clearly sexism at work. Friedman had to put his foot down and really chew some people out before they decided to give her the degree.

Yes, I think in the absence of professional norms, you have a lot more room for power plays, for unfairness, for prejudice. That said, I think the professional norms can get too rigid, to the point where you cultivate groupthink and you close out the possibility of new perspectives, new ideas, new paths. This was definitely a moment of formation.

COWEN: How do you think about all the work Milton did with women? Anna Schwartz most of all, but his ideas on consumption, he drew from several women researchers. That was unusual back then. Obviously, the work with Rose. Is he, in your mind, a protofeminist? Or this is coincidence, or what was it for him?

BURNS: Sort of neither. I think you wouldn’t have Milton Friedman without these women. Sometimes I give a talk called “Milton Friedman Was a Woman” because I think if you pulled all the women out of his life, you’d have a good economist, but I don’t know that you’d have a great economist. I don’t think you would because they did several things.

What they really did was provide a counterpoint to his natural inclinations. Take A Monetary History. This would not really have been a narrative or a history. It would’ve been a bunch of charts and graphs about the money supply. It would’ve been closer to, say, Kuznets’ studies of national income. It’s really Schwartz that has a love for history, that puts it into a narrative that convinces him to make it a much longer story. That’s why that book resonates — because it’s not just data. It’s a narrative. It’s a story.

When it comes to the Theory of the Consumption Function, he was basically drawing on the women’s world of consumption economics, which was something that had been a big part of the field, but because of this professional process, which also was driven by men, there was this machismo to it. A lot of men had turned away from consumption economics. Since Friedman had not, he had an advantage. He was zigging where everyone was zagging.

Now, why was Friedman able to do this? Was he more enlightened than other economists of his day? I would say both yes and no. I had some anecdotes and stories that he was not feminist in his behavior. On the other hand, compared to economists of his day, he very much was. I didn’t find any letter that mentioned anything negative about any of his collaborators as women. That’s not true for other economists. Some cases — I think it’s Samuelson who will write letters supposedly in support of his female students that turn out to actually be very negative and very sexist in tone.

I tend to think that Friedman had a way of missing some social cues and social norms in ways that could be detrimental. When it came to the women working with him, he had an ability that maybe others didn’t, to see the person before he saw the woman. If it was a very smart woman, he would recognize, first and foremost, that this was a smart woman. Secondly, register that this was a woman, and then maybe that would come with some of the supposed limitations. But he really was generous and supportive of the women in his life as intellectuals.

I think that’s his secret sauce because no one else is really doing it at the time. It gives him new perspectives. When you look at the work he was cited for in the Nobel Prize, most of it has a major woman collaborator: A Monetary History, A Theory of the Consumption Function. There’s a third, which isn’t coming to mind, but those two would not have been done without a female collaborator. I knew nothing about this when I started, and I was like, “This is strange.”

I also think it’s why he wrote books. He wouldn’t have written books without these collaborators. I think books still are very, very powerful. Even in a field that’s moving toward papers, books retain their power.

COWEN: Why did Friedman oppose the courtesy appointment of Hayek in the economics department at Chicago?

BURNS: I don’t have a ton of information about that, because one of the interesting things that happens, right when you would think Friedman and Hayek’s relationship is the most important, Hayek comes — I believe it’s basically 1950 to 1960 he’s at Chicago. Right when he arrives at Chicago, you lose the paper trail because now he’s there, so there’s not a lot of discussion.

My sense is that he didn’t consider Hayek an economist because he wasn’t empirical enough. When Friedman turned away from mathematical economics, he was turning away from theoretical models. He wasn’t turning away from data per se, and he really believed you had to have theory, which for him, was price theory; empirics, such as his collaborators gathered through the study of consumption; and you had to test that theory with the empirics.

He saw Hayek — although Hayek really did influence and teach him intellectually, I would say — he saw him not as a proper economist because he wasn’t doing that empirical research. He wasn’t trying to test his theories with empirical data sets. I don’t think he wanted Hayek training graduate students. He was happy to put Hayek on the syllabus, happy to have him teaching seminars, very involved with him in the broader intellectual endeavors. But I think he had an idea of what and how economics should be, and Hayek didn’t fit into that at that point.

COWEN: How is it you think that Friedman’s influence differed in Britain compared to the United States?

BURNS: How did it differ in Britain?

COWEN: I see every country has its own version of Milton Friedman. They’re all a bit inaccurate, but he had influence in many places. How is Britain different?

BURNS: Well, I think Britain — one, it had a preexisting set of ideas that was called monetarism, which actually wasn’t Friedman-inspired but linked up with him very closely. I think Friedman actually had more and less influence.

The presidential lecture he gave in 1967, saying there wasn’t a long-run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment — there are definitely several key figures in the British political establishment who found that made a big impact on their thinking because they felt like they were living that. “We’ve been trying to spend money to bring down unemployment, and now we’ve spent all this money, and unemployment is still going up, and inflation is going up.” In a lot of ways, Friedman seemed to be explaining what was happening in Britain, and it happened sooner.

On the other hand, he also became a symbolic figure very quickly in British politics because the British monetary system is different. It was different at that time, so his advice wasn’t technically suitable in many ways.

Secondly, he became a much more prominent figure after the Nobel Prize and after his controversy over his connection to the Pinochet regime in Chile. He then became a whipping boy of left and right. He does have, one, a substantive intellectual impact, and two, a symbolic impact.

I don’t think his celebrations of individual freedom maybe have the same cultural resonance in Britain as they do in the United States. In the United States, he’s in some ways tapping into the rugged-individualism, frontier spirit. We’re Americans, and we’re free. He’s got more of that to play with than I think he did have in Britain. You don’t see “capitalism” and “freedom” falling off people’s lips in the same way in England as it did in the United States.

COWEN: There’s a debate in one of the episodes of Free to Choose where Peter Jay, who is British, takes on Milton Friedman. I don’t know if you remember this. Jay says, “Well, Milton, you’re always inconsistent. You cite utility when you want to make an argument, but when utility’s not on your side, you switch back to liberty. Which is it? Which one is your master?” Was Peter Jay right? Was Milton wrong? What’s your view?

BURNS: I love that exchange because if you recollect, Peter Jay keeps pushing, and finally Friedman says — I think this is verbatim — “Freedom is my God.” I was like, “Wow, freedom is your God.” I expected the lightning bolt to come down. It was very intense, but I think that is ultimately it. Friedman didn’t want to believe you had to choose between freedom and greater prosperity, between an unregulated economy and widespread differentials of wealth.

He really didn’t want to make that choice because, one, freedom was his God, and two, he was not an egalitarian, but he definitely was concerned about those who had less, and he wanted there to be fewer poor people. He didn’t really want to confront that tension. He spent a lot of time trying to massage it. I think that’s where his interest in what we would call UBI comes from.

The other thing I really do want to stress is, in his era, it looked plausible that you didn’t have to choose. In other words, it’s the era of the convergence of incomes. It’s the era where, as countries develop economically, their income inequality goes down, so he’s seeing a very different set of figures than we look at today.

As a result, he was much more optimistic that the more capitalism spread, the more inequality would decline, the better off everybody would be. He really didn’t wrestle very much, although he started to a bit at the end of his life, with the conundrum, what if capitalism spreads and things get worse for a lot of people? What do I do then?

COWEN: You mentioned Friedman in Chile. What’s the bottom line on that whole episode, in your opinion?

BURNS: I think most of it was manufactured as a campaign against Friedman because ultimately, his impact was similar to what any Western-trained economist would have had. He was not the architect of the junta. He was not particularly connected to Pinochet. He came in after an economic catastrophe and prescribed what pretty much any Western-trained economist would’ve prescribed to stop inflation.

He was then tagged as the architect and Western endorser of the regime, which was not the case. I think he came to stand in for people’s discomfort with the idea that the Nixon administration had perhaps supported the coup.

There’s another piece of it, that the dream of Allende was there could be a peaceful road to socialism. The coup seemed to suggest that that was not true, that the peaceful road to socialism could not happen. If the coup was not inevitable because it was manufactured by Western economists and Western governments, then perhaps we could get back on the vía chilena and make our way to the peaceful redistribution of property and power and the success of a socialist government.

I think he got really tangled up in all these questions about, is it possible to have a peaceful transition to a socialist or communist government? Making Friedman the problem enabled you to focus on Friedman or Nixon, rather than the very real problems created by the Allende government in Chile.

COWEN: You used the word prescribed. Just physically, literally, what did he do? What’s the thing he did there?

BURNS: Oh, yes. I can talk about that, for sure. He actually didn’t do that much, which is interesting. I’ll get a little bit granular. Basically, Pinochet takes over in a country where the state sector has expanded dramatically, and inflation — I think it’s almost 600 percent. I could be wrong. It’s hundreds of percent. It makes our stress about 6 percent inflation — really puts it in perspective.

When the junta comes in, they basically keep doing everything they’ve been doing in terms of state control of the economy. They reprivatize a little bit, but they don’t really know what to do. Say the socialist governor of the mine is replaced by a military governor of the mine, and then nothing is improving economically.

About a year, a year and a half in, there’s a changing of the guard internally in the Chilean regime. A group of economists — several of whom did have Chicago training — basically are able to get the ear of the dictator and say, “Look, we need to do things differently. We need to reprivatize. We need to open markets to international trade, and we need to do all this stuff.” Pinochet basically says, “Okay, let’s do it.” It’s at that point that they’re like, “Let’s bring in Milton Friedman.”

Then Friedman comes in. The policy has been decided, and basically, his role is to speak to what I jokingly call the Chilean deep state. He goes around and he meets with all the military functionaries who will carry out these policies. He explains in his very lucid way, here’s why this is the right medicine for Chile. He does interviews. He meets a lot of different people.

He meets Pinochet very briefly. He tells him, “You have to cut spending to cut inflation.” He also reportedly says, according to someone who is in the meeting, “If you give the people economic freedom, eventually, it’s going to mean political freedom.” Apparently, Pinochet is like, “Yeah. yeah, whatever. Sure.” What I found in the records that I read, the big question that everyone had for Friedman was, “This is going to be too painful. We can’t do this. This is going to hurt too many people.”

Even in the military regime, they are worried. “If we cut all the state supports that have been created, and we try to stop printing money and stop inflation, this is going to cause a huge amount of economic pain.” Friedman’s like a broken record. “Yes, but you have to do this, and the quicker you do it, the quicker it’ll be over. Cut the spending, provide emergency economic support, and you’ll get through it.” Basically, he uses the metaphor of cutting off a dog’s tail, which is a horrific metaphor, but he says, “You’ve got to do it all at once. You can’t drag it out.”

I would say his function is to certify and explain a policy change that has already happened. He is basically a big name flown in to tell everybody, “Here’s a new program. Here’s why it’s going to work. Let’s get psyched and do it.” He’s not the mastermind in any way.

The real reason his presence there is so controversial is the Nobel Prize, which is awarded, I think, about a year later. The really unfortunate part is, the Nobel Prize announcement comes just a few weeks after Pinochet’s goons have assassinated a regime critic on the streets of Washington, DC. They blow up his car on the streets of Washington, DC. Then a couple weeks later, Friedman wins the Nobel Prize.

Now, there’s no connection between these events, but it appears that these right-thinking people of the Western world are patting the dictator on the head. That’s how it’s framed. Nobody cares about what’s happening in Chile. Look, they’re celebrating this economist who’s somehow responsible for what has happened. It all gets mushed together to make a political point.

COWEN: What’s the future of Milton Friedman, say, 30, 40 years from now? Where will the reputation be? University of Chicago is no longer Friedmanite, right? We know that. There are fewer outposts of Friedmanite-thinking than there had been. Will he be underrated or somehow reinvented or what?

BURNS: Let me look into my crystal ball. I don’t think the name will have faded. I think there are still names that people read. People still read Keynes and Mill and figures like that to see what did they say in their day that was so influential. I think that Friedman has got into the water and into the air a bit. I do some work on tracing out his influence.

Within economics, no one’s going to say, “Oh, I’m a Friedmanite,” or fewer people are, but this is someone whose major work was done half a century or more ago, so I don’t think that’s surprising. It would be surprising if economics had been at a standstill as Friedman still called the tune. When you think about the way we accord importance to the modern Federal Reserve, of course, there were things that happened in the world, but Friedman’s ideas did so much to shape that understanding.

He’s still in policymakers’ minds. He’s still in the monetary policy establishment’s minds, even if they’re not fully following him. I think we’re in the middle of a big reckoning now. You saw all the debate about M2 and the pandemic and monetary spending. I don’t know where it’s all going to settle out. It’s a more complicated world than the one that Friedman looked at. I tend to think he is an essential thinker, that the basics of what he talked about are going to be known 50 years from now, for sure.

COWEN: Did Milton Friedman have friends?

BURNS: He did. He had lots of friends.

COWEN: Who was his best friend? Not colleagues, not co-authors, but other friends?

BURNS: Well, that’s an interesting thing because most of his friends were his colleagues and were those in agreement with him ideologically. He had a friendship with someone named Leo Rosten, who was a humorist.

COWEN: A great writer.

BURNS: A humorist in American-Jewish life.

COWEN: He wrote a lot of books about Yiddish culture.

BURNS: Yes, exactly. He was friends with him.

COWEN: But Rosten agreed with Friedman mostly, right?

BURNS: Yes.

COWEN: If you read Rosten on the Industrial Revolution, it sounds very Friedman.

BURNS: [laughs] He probably glossed a lot of what he was hearing from Friedman. He apparently did have a friendship with Daniel Boorstin, who’s a historian at the University of Chicago. I would say either George Stigler or Aaron Director was probably his closest friend.

Aaron Director was his brother-in-law, and George Stigler was his grad school friend and eventually became his colleague. This is one thing I really noticed in the book, that for Friedman, friendship and ideological sympathy and commitment to a certain political vision — they’re all intertwined.

He had cordial relationships with a lot of different people, but they weren’t quite friends. Even, I think, the great crisis in his friendship with Arthur Burns is a policy disagreement. For Friedman, that policy disagreement just calls into question the whole friendship, although he very quickly tries to reestablish that connection. He won’t let that connection go, but the fact that it is so stressed by their disagreement over monetary policy, I think is really indicative. Yes, he walked, talked, breathed economics, all the time.

COWEN: Your other biography — it’s of Ayn Rand. Again, it’s called Goddess of the Market: Ayn Rand and the American Right. Before the novels, was she a good screenwriter?

BURNS: Let’s see. I think she probably was. She had success in a pretty competitive industry. Most of them tended to be these melodramatic plots. I actually liked the film We the Living. They did a fairly good version of it.

The other thing that’s hard to say is, she didn’t compose a ton of original screenplays. What she would do is take an existing screenplay and tart it up a little bit, make it more interesting. I don’t know that we’ll ever fully . . . That would be a project, actually, to try to excavate which films did she have a hand in?

The fact that she went from penniless immigrant to having a creative role in one of the major studios of her time — there must have been something that was recognized. Also, again, as a woman in an era when that wouldn’t have counted in her favor by any means.

COWEN: Which do you think is the best of the novels? Some would say least bad, but either way.

BURNS: Yes, like I said, I’m partial to We the Living. It’s set in Russia during the Revolution, so it has that historical flavor I like. It’s sort of a roman à clef. It’s characters and family she knew. While the central love triangle is quite imaginative and will strike many readers as not true to human nature, the ancillary characters, I think, do ring true. Her flights of imagination were tempered by the fact that she was working from this material. It’s just a fascinating glimpse into Russia a hundred years ago. It’s long, but it’s not quite so long.

The pity with Atlas Shrugged is she was uneditable by that time, and she really needed to be edited. [laughs]

COWEN: Sex scenes in Atlas Shrugged and Fountainhead — what do you make of them as a reader today?

BURNS: I think they’re part projection. I think they also can be very usefully read as part of the romantic genre. If you were to pick up a romance novel in the supermarket, you would find a very similar plot structure. It’s very much against our sensibilities, the rape as romance, coercion as romance, but again, if you read a dime-store romance novel, this is a trope that’s very common. I think she was pulling on these tropes, and then she was imagining this heroic manly man, that if she actually ever met in real life, she would not be attracted to and probably not even be able to tolerate, but in her imagination, this could be an idealized partner.

COWEN: I recall at age 13 visiting the Foundation for Economic Education, and Leonard Read boasting to me in his office that he had Ayn Rand on his desk and pointing to where that happened. What was the equilibrium in her love life? How did that work?

BURNS: Let’s see. I’m sure she flirted with Leonard Read; that would make sense. The equilibrium was she was always drawn to younger men, and that is true from the beginning. She was very much drawn to her husband, and she was the aggressor in that relationship. Then there are a couple before Nathaniel Branden, who was her student and then her collaborator and her longtime lover, I think 25 years her junior.

There are a couple of other young men who she was testing as potential romantic partners. I found a couple reminiscences at the archive. She would start a friendship. They would come visit her, and then in retrospect, they were like, “You know what, if I had wanted to pursue this romantically, she would have been willing,” or “She was trying to set me up. She was trying to seduce me, but she was going a little slow, and I didn’t know what was going on.”

I think there are maybe two people that were in that position before Nathaniel Branden. Then I think once she was with Branden, she was pretty content with him. She wasn’t looking elsewhere. I think her equilibrium was what she achieved briefly, which was a doting and supportive husband and an exciting secret lover, much younger than her. She had it briefly, but it didn’t last.

COWEN: What was the role of the Roy Childs “Open Letter to Ayn Rand”?

BURNS: That’s a great moment. Roy Childs writes this letter to Ayn Rand. He’s basically saying, if I remember correctly, “Be anarcho-capitalist. You haven’t gone far enough. If you follow the logic of your thought, there should be no state whatsoever.” She wasn’t really paying attention, and what did she call them? Hippies of the right. She hated anarchists. She hated libertarians. By the end of her life, she hated anyone who liked her, which was a difficult position to be in.

I don’t think that it had an impact on her, but it was one of these documents that said, “To all of you who like Ayn Rand but feel like she hasn’t gone far enough, let’s go there together, and we can appreciate her without feeling like we have to stay with her understanding of the state, or her clinging to the atavistic state.”

My feeling on both her and Friedman in their not going all the way to anarchy — I think it has something to do with their backgrounds. In Rand’s case, living through revolution and living in Europe. In Friedman’s case, a very real consciousness of his Jewish identity.

For both of them, while they felt the state often discriminated against minorities, I think they were more fearful of what would happen without a state in a situation of anarchy, in which they would be identified as racial or ethnic or religious minorities. I think they had a visceral fear of that for themselves and for any other community that would be in that situation. That kept both of them from saying, “Blow everything up, and let’s just see what happens.”

COWEN: Roy, later in his life, admitted Rand was right, and that his own open letter was wrong.

BURNS: I didn’t know that. That’s interesting.

COWEN: Yes. Did Rand and Friedman, Milton Friedman, know each other?

BURNS: They did, and what did Friedman call her? Something like a terrible and dogmatic woman who did a great deal of good.

To go back to the big schism between Ayn Rand and Leonard Read — Leonard Read was an early publisher of libertarian pamphlets and materials — came when he published Friedman and Stigler’s Roofs or Ceilings, which was an economic analysis of rent control. They were analyzing rent control from the position of economic efficiency, like rent control is economically inefficient.

They were also philosophically opposed to rent control, but they decided, really, strategically, rather than get into this whole philosophical battle, we’re just going to talk about this being economically inefficient. Policy choice and policy argument.

Ayn Rand understood that Leonard Read had agreed to use her as a kind of ideological gatekeeper, and that he was, according to her, going to show everything the foundation published to her, and she would give it a thumbs up or a thumbs down, and then it would be published. This may or may not have been the arrangement. Whatever it was, Read did not follow that process. He published Roofs or Ceilings. Ayn Rand read it, and she hit the roof.

You have this fascinating situation where this one titan of the American right, Ayn Rand, is calling another figurehead of American conservatism, Milton Friedman, a communist. She thought that Stigler and Friedman were communists because she could tell they were using this utilitarian argument and scrupulously avoiding any moral argument. She viewed that as a veiled way of neutralizing discussion of economic issues such that you couldn’t make an ethical case on behalf of private property. So, she became livid. She and Read had a huge fight, letters back and forth. She’s going to have nothing to do with Leonard Read.

Now interestingly, Read and Friedman also had a huge fight over this. Part of it was because the original version of the pamphlet — although it was mostly utilitarian in its argument, it did have a nod to the idea that Friedman and Stigler would like more equality than there is now. They said something like, “Even if you want more equality the way we do, you should still support this on efficiency grounds.”

This is that influence of Henry Simons again, who was much more egalitarian than Friedman, and when he was close to Simons, Friedman had a more egalitarian cast. Well, Leonard Read had a henchman, Orval Watts, who was very, very — almost a social Darwinist, I would say. Watts did not want that in there, so Watts cut that out.

Friedman and Stigler said, “No, no, no, you need to keep it in there.” They said, “Okay, okay, we’ll keep it in.” Then they footnoted it and said something like, “We disagree with this.” Then they published an abridged version of the pamphlet that cut it out entirely. Friedman and Stigler were so mad, they wouldn’t talk to Read for like five years.

To me, this episode is so illuminating because it’s a question of how do we, in 1946 — coming out of the World War II era, coming out of the Depression, coming out of the success of the New Deal — how do we talk about economics, equality, and fairness? Should we talk about it in the old idiom? “You get what you deserve.” Should we talk about it in a new idiom? “Let’s help everyone have the basics.”

Or should we not talk about it at all, and use the language of economics about what is the most efficient, which ultimately will redound to the greatest good for the greatest number? It’s not really worked out. People have really different positions on this.

This question of rent control is really huge. A huge percentage of housing stock in the United States was rent-controlled at that time due to the war. There’s an enormous housing shortage. This was a really big issue. It was coming up before Congress, so everyone kind of got in, and they couldn’t figure out how to talk about it. They just couldn’t figure out how to talk about it, period. That’s like the big explosion moment. I think it’s ’46. In another decade, they’ll be closer to figuring out these questions.

COWEN: What do you think of the Chris Sciabarra argument that Rand drew a lot of her basic ideas from earlier Russian philosophy?

BURNS: I think there’s probably a good deal to it. I don’t know that I would lay it all. He really emphasizes — I think it’s the Russian Silver Age. To my mind, the clearest through line for her is Friedrich Nietzsche, who would’ve been a presence in Russian intellectual circles but is not necessarily Russian. The Fountainhead, in its original conception, had a headnote from Nietzsche in each of its four sections. She pulled those right before publication because she thought it was too much.

I would say, this idea — she loved the phrase from Nietzsche, “The noble soul has reverence for itself.” She loved all those ideas, and they’ve just resonated with her very powerfully. Even in her unpublished work, she really takes some a bit to the edge of madness. They’re more tempered in The Fountainhead. I’m like, “Yes, she’s a Russian novelist.” Look at those books. They’re huge. They’re panoramic. She’s very convinced of her role. She’s very convinced of the power of intelligentsia.

There was a complete conviction that a salon of committed intellectuals could cause profound social and intellectual change, which, of course, she had seen happen. I definitely think she’s part of that tradition, but also, she’s not just Russian. She’s Russian Jewish, so I think there’s a counterpoint to that in her concern with the powers of the state, and her focus on rationality, and her celebration of other cultures, high European cultures beyond Russia. She, in the end, would say, “Russia, it’s just a mystical state.”

It’s interesting because, in recent years, when we’ve seen the glories, the fantasies of Mother Russia, or the role of the Russian Orthodox Church, the mythic importance of Kyiv, or whatever it may be, I think back to Ayn Rand grumbling, “It’s just a mystical state, and they’re all obsessed with mysticism.” I’m like, “Well.”

COWEN: She was right. Right?

BURNS: Yes. [laughs] Maybe so.

COWEN: How did Rand and Mises get along?

BURNS: Rand and Mises — it’s a complicated story. Some of your viewers and readers who are more into this literature might have heard of an anecdote where supposedly they screamed at each other at a party. That appears not to be true. That appears to be a rumor started by William F. Buckley to cause trouble.

She actually loved Ludwig von Mises. She said, on several occasions, “My economics is from Mises. Everything I know about economics, I know from Mises.” They’re both thinkers who have this rational framework, who have a few axiomatic first principles that they then build a system upon. I think she really didn’t know a ton about economics and hadn’t thought about it until she read Mises.

In person, they did tend to clash. They’re both pretty difficult personalities, sort of in the same way, but the letters between them are always respectful. Mises was one of the few living people that she didn’t cut down to her students, that she recommended her students read. If you read the Objectivist Newsletter, there’s mentions of him and articles on him. I think that was an important connection.

COWEN: Why is it, in the 20th century in America, fiction seems to have been so much more important for the left than for the right? Especially if you take away Rand. Why that huge difference?

BURNS: That’s such an interesting question. It may have to do with a general truism that this artistic and creative life is often a bohemian life as well, in which traditions — whether they be traditional marriage or traditional monogamy — things like that are questioned as part of the creative process. It seems to be where things ferment. If you are a person who values tradition and values established norms and social practices, that may not be an environment conducive to creating imaginary worlds. So, I think you need a culture to support artistic creation and fiction creation.

Once a culture tips a certain way, it kind of goes that way. I could certainly imagine societies — and perhaps your listeners will know ones, too — where the production of fiction is done more by conservative writers or thinkers. I would imagine they have a culture to support that, even if it’s just a city, a university, a small tradition, a literary school. But I do think, as much as creativity is individual, it flourishes in community, so if you don’t have that community, it doesn’t get written.

COWEN: Why are there so few successful businesswomen in American fiction? There’s Rand, there’s Gone with the Wind, but very little else comes to mind.

BURNS: Oh, like why are there so few depictions of women as successful businessmen? [laughs] There we go. I just said it myself.

COWEN: Whatever you want to call it.

BURNS: Fiction is trying to reflect the human experience. To this date, there’s just been more men who’ve plied their life’s work in business than women. I think that’s part of it. It’s too bad. I think Rand’s created some memorable characters because of that. On the other hand, there is a way in which, sure, her characters are women, but they’re not engaging in pursuits that the vast majority of women engage in, such as motherhood. They’re kind of living masculine lives, although she’s describing them as highly feminine. They’re a bit of a blend, in some ways.

COWEN: Did Milton Friedman read much fiction?

BURNS: Not that I can tell. There are some stories where Rose wanted him to come to the opera with her, and he was like, “Well, can I bring a book so I can read if I get bored?” He didn’t really appreciate culture. Also, Anna Schwartz had a story where he was spending a semester in Paris, and she was like, “Oh, the museums will be so wonderful.” He said to her, “Why would I go to a museum?” Just literally didn’t know why he would spend his time that way. Like I said, he enjoyed the fiction of Leo Rosten. That’s really the only fiction I’ve heard of him mentioning.

COWEN: The literature on amusia, which is a condition where you’re not able to enjoy music, sometimes cites Friedman as having had amusia. I’m not sure that’s confirmed. Do you know anything about that?

BURNS: No, I don’t. That’s interesting. I’m not familiar with that literature. That does make sense, though, with this story. I wonder if maybe they saw that story where Rose — she loved the symphony, she loved the opera, and he was basically, “Okay, fine. I’ll go, but I need to bring my own entertainment along.”

What he did for recreation — he really enjoyed woodworking. Aaron Director was a skilled woodworker, and his basement had a whole setup. I think Friedman built all the furniture for their first home by hand. He liked building, he played tennis, and he liked skiing. His relaxation was with his hands or physical in nature. I think otherwise, when he was reading, he was reading for work.

COWEN: I also learned from your book, by the way, that Aaron Director and Mark Rothko had been childhood friends. That’s remarkable.

BURNS: Isn’t that fascinating? It’s really fascinating. I have to say, there’s a historian — I think he’s at the University of Rhode Island — Robert Van Horn, who’s really excavated a lot of the early life of Aaron Director, and it’s absolutely fascinating.

COWEN: Very last question or set of questions: What will you do next?

BURNS: That’s a great question. I have a couple of book projects in mind. One is to just look back a little bit more, rather than write a biography of an essential figure, to put them together into a broader story of the intellectual history of American conservatism or something like that. That’s one. More of a synthetic history, I would say. There’s been such an outpouring of literature on the subject. Some days I think it would be fun to bring it all together. Other days I think it’s going to be maybe not so fun [laughs] to have to pick through all that.

I’m also interested in writing sort of a history of postmodernism because I’ve been teaching an intellectual history class here at Stanford that’s been tracing it across the century, and I think that’s potentially really interesting. It would be quite different than what I’ve done thus far. I’ll have to wait and see — do I want to strike out for new terrain or keep plowing the field I’m in? Stay tuned, is all I have to say on that. [laughs]

COWEN: Just one follow-up question on that. Many of us observing history have the sense that the intellectual tradition within the American right has been in decline for several decades. (A) Do you agree? (B) If so, what, most fundamentally, is driving that change?

BURNS: I think it’s a less vigorously intellectual culture. One thing I sometimes face with undergraduates is, they’re genuinely surprised when I say, “Well, yes, the conservatives had all the ideas in the 20th century. The conservatives really made an impact because they came up with all these ideas that were really powerful and important.” It doesn’t really compute because the conservatism they’ve grown up with is not driven by ideas in any meaningful way. I think that’s certainly true.

I would say one of the reasons it’s happened is that conservatism became an establishment, and then you have a set of greatest hits, and you have a variety of ways you can make your living within this establishment, provided you adhere to the greatest hits. There’s not a ton of incentives to do things differently. I do think there’s a lot of ideological ferment on the right or amid conservatives right now. It’s heavy on ideas. It’s often in internet forms that are not deep engagement with ideas, I would say, in the same way as when you’re reading books and magazines. I think it’s faster and more rapid.

It’s really interesting. There’s much more competition in the realm of ideas than there was. Besides reading a book or going to college, you can get ideas — they’re coming out of everywhere, coming out of the ether. I think that’s going to lend less coherence. You can have a lot of people who are intellectual leaders of smaller tribes rather than having a couple of the big leaders that everyone’s heard of — Friedman, Hayek, this and that.

I just think we’re in a more fragmented place. I tend to attribute it to the media environment we’re in, which probably isn’t going away anytime soon. So the question is, can we live and thrive in this fragmented-attention ecosphere, or are we going to recreate something akin to the three big networks [laughs] to filter and manage all the information we have? I think we’ll see that evolve, or not, over the next 50 years.

COWEN: Again, everyone, the book is Milton Friedman: The Last Conservative by Jennifer Burns, B-U-R-N-S. Highly recommended. Jennifer, thank you very much.

BURNS: Thanks so much, Tyler.